首页
登录
职称英语
Between the invention of agriculture and the commercial revolution that mark
Between the invention of agriculture and the commercial revolution that mark
游客
2025-04-23
19
管理
问题
Between the invention of agriculture and the commercial revolution that marked the end of the Middle Ages, wealth and technology developed slowly indeed. Medieval historians tell of the centuries it took for key inventions like the watermill or the heavy plow to diffuse across the landscape. During this period, increases in technology led to increases in the population, with little if any appearing as an improvement in the median standard of living.
Even the first century of the industrial revolution produced more "improvements" than "revolutions" in standards of living. With the railroad and the spinning and weaving of textiles as important exceptions, most innovations of that period were innovations in how goods were produced and transported, and in new kinds of capital, but not in consumer goods. Standards of living improved but styles of life remained much the same.
The eighteenth and nineteenth centuries saw a faster and different kind of change. For the first time, technological capability outran population growth and natural resource scarcity. By the last quarter of the nineteenth century, the typical inhabitant of the leading economies—a British, a Belgian, an American, or an Australian had perhaps three times the standard of living of someone in a pre-industrial economy.
Still, so slow was the pace of change that people, or at least aristocratic intellectuals, could think of their predecessors of some two thousand years before as effectively their contemporaries. Marcus Tullius Cicero, a Roman aristocrat and politician, might have felt more or less at home in the company of Thomas Jefferson. The plows were better in Jefferson’s time. Sailing ships were much improved. However, these might have been insufficient to create a sense of a qualitative change in the order of life for the elite. Moreover, being a slave of Jefferson was probably a lot like being a slave of Cicero.
So slow was the pace of change that intellectuals in the early nineteenth century debated whether the industrial revolution was worthwhile, whether it was an improvement or a degeneration in the standard of living. Opinions were genuinely divided, with as optimistic a liberal as John Stuart Mill coming down on the "pessimist" side as late as the end of the 1840s.
In the twentieth century, however, standards of living exploded. In the twentieth century, the magnitude of the growth in material wealth has been so great as to make it nearly impossible to measure. Consider a sample of consumer goods available through Montgomery Ward in 1895 when a one-speed bicycle cost $65. Since then, the price of a bicycle measured in "nominal" dollars has more than doubled (as a result of inflation). Today, the bicycle is much less expensive in terms of the measure that truly counts, its "real" price: the work and sweat needed to earn its east. In 1895, it took perhaps 260 hours’ worth of the average American worker’s production to amass enough money to buy a one-speed bicycle. Today an average American worker can buy one—and of higher quality—for less than 8 hours worth of production.
On the bicycle standard (measuring wealth by counting up how many bicycles the labor can buy) the average American worker today is 36 times richer than his or her counterpart was in 1895. Other commodities would tell a different story. An office chair has become 12.5 times cheaper in terms of the time it takes the average worker to produce enough to pay for it. A Steinway piano or an accordion is only twice as cheap. A silver teaspoon is 25 percent more expensive.
Thus the answer to the question "How much wealthier are we today than our counterparts of a century ago?" depends on which commodities you view as important. For many personal services—having a butler to answer the door and polish your silver spoons—you would find little difference in average wealth between 1895 and 1990: an hour of a butler’s time costs about the same then as now. For mass-produced manufactured goods—like bicycles—we are wealthier by as much as 36 times. [br] A bicycle today, generally speaking,
选项
A、requires more work and sweat because fewer people work to produce it.
B、is comparatively less in real price than a bicycle in the nineteenth century.
C、needs to be considered in terms of "nominal" costs.
D、is cheaper in America than any other western country.
答案
B
解析
转载请注明原文地址:https://www.tihaiku.com/zcyy/4049994.html
相关试题推荐
Between5,000millionand4,000millionyearsagotheEarthwasformed,By3
Between5,000millionand4,000millionyearsagotheEarthwasformed,By3
Between5,000millionand4,000millionyearsagotheEarthwasformed,By3
Between5,000millionand4,000millionyearsagotheEarthwasformed,By3
Thedifferencebetweenavianfluandhumanfluthatshouldbecommandingour
Whenaninventionismade,theinventorhasthreepossible【C1】______ofac
Whenaninventionismade,theinventorhasthreepossible【C1】______ofac
Whenaninventionismade,theinventorhasthreepossible【C1】______ofac
Whenaninventionismade,theinventorhasthreepossible【C1】______ofac
Whenaninventionismade,theinventorhasthreepossible【C1】______ofac
随机试题
A.widerB.rapidlyC.satisfactoryD.biggerE.objectsF.genuinelyG.
[originaltext]M:Howdoyouandyourhousemateslikethenewco-op?I’mthinking
连墙件在脚手架中的作用是:不论有风无风均受力,既承传水平风荷载,又承传因约束脚手
B提示举反例说明,符合题目条件的级数有两种不同的情况:收敛,发散。 综合以上两例,满足条件的级数未必收敛。
关于窒息目前诊断参考指标是哪一项A.羊水Ⅲ度 B.肌张力低下 C.出生后需正
B由题意可知,|A|=3,则A*A=AA*=3E。在等式ABA*=2BA*+E两边同时右乘
关于投资者参与证券交易所债券质押式回购,下列说法中错误的是()。A.质押冻结期
专用存款账户用于各项专用资金的收付,适用于()等专项管理和使用的资金。A、更新
根据下列资料回答问题。 2010年,我国进出口贸易总额为29727.6亿美元
《共同纲领》
最新回复
(
0
)